Forbidden City in Beijing

China’s economic model, a blend of state control and market forces, continues to fascinate and confound observers. How did this unique system evolve? Are the levers of power wielded by Beijing today truly novel, or are they echoes of an ancient playbook? To understand the present, we must delve into the past, exploring the very DNA of Chinese state power: its fiscal history. Decoding the Fiscal Secrets of the Central Empire, a compelling new book, offers a unique lens through which to examine this intricate story.

Published in 2017 by Lujiang Publishing House and penned by Guo Jianlong (郭建龙), Decoding the Fiscal Secrets of the Central Empire (中央帝国的财政密码) quickly became a bestseller in China, capturing the zeitgeist of a nation grappling with its economic identity. Boasting an impressive 8.3 rating on Douban, China’s equivalent of Goodreads, the book resonated deeply with Chinese readers, sparking online discussions about the long history of state intervention in the economy. It’s not just a dry historical account; it’s a narrative woven with intriguing stories, offering a fresh perspective on familiar historical figures and events.

Central to Guo’s analysis are three core financial tools employed by successive dynasties: State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs), Public Land Ownership, and Financial Monopolies (with a particular emphasis on currency). While these tools might seem like hallmarks of modern China, Guo reveals their deep roots in the empire’s fiscal history, tracing their evolution across two millennia. From the salt and iron monopolies of the Han Dynasty to the intricate paper money systems of the Song and Yuan, these instruments of state power have shaped the trajectory of Chinese civilization.

Guo’s central thesis is both simple and profound: the rise and fall of Chinese dynasties are inextricably linked to their fiscal health. These three financial tools aren’t just about generating revenue; they are mechanisms for the state to acquire and maintain power, influencing everything from military strength to social stability. This resonates powerfully with current debates about China’s economic model. Are SOEs a source of strength or a drag on innovation? Does public land ownership empower the state or disenfranchise citizens? And to what extent can a government manipulate its currency to achieve its political goals? Decoding the Fiscal Secrets of the Central Empire offers a timely and insightful exploration of these perennial questions, shedding light on China’s past, present, and future.

The Fiscal DNA of Chinese Dynasties

Part 1: From Emperors to Eunuchs: The Seeds of Fiscal Instability

The Han Dynasty, a period often romanticized for its prosperity and cultural achievements, provides a compelling case study in the perils of fiscal overreach. Emperor Wu, a ruler of grand ambitions, embarked on a series of extensive military campaigns that stretched the empire’s finances to their breaking point. These campaigns, while expanding the Han’s territorial reach, came at a steep price, demanding innovative (and often controversial) fiscal measures. Emperor Wu turned to two primary tools to fund his military adventures: state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and currency manipulation.

The creation of SOEs, particularly the salt and iron monopolies, marked a significant shift in the role of the state. Previously, the Han government had largely adhered to a laissez-faire approach to the economy. But faced with mounting military expenses, Emperor Wu saw the potential for profit in controlling essential commodities. By nationalizing the salt and iron industries, he aimed to create a steady stream of revenue directly for the imperial coffers. This provided a short-term solution to his immediate financial needs, but sowed the seeds of long-term economic distortion.

In addition to SOEs, Emperor Wu dabbled in currency manipulation, introducing “leather money” (皮幣) and “white metal” (白金) coinage. Leather money, essentially pieces of white deerskin adorned with purple markings, was assigned an exorbitant value, far exceeding the intrinsic worth of the material. White metal, an alloy of silver and tin, similarly had its official value inflated, creating an arbitrage opportunity. These measures were essentially thinly veiled attempts to generate revenue through inflation. However, they quickly backfired, causing widespread confusion and distrust in the market. Merchants, seeing the artificial inflation, either hoarded valuable commodities or resorted to counterfeiting, exacerbating the instability. This illustrates the principle of “bad money drives out good money”: when a government mandates the circulation of an overvalued currency alongside a more stable one, the latter disappears from circulation, either hoarded or melted down for its material value.

While Emperor Wu’s fiscal maneuvers provided temporary relief, they created a cascade of long-term problems. Inflation, a direct consequence of his currency manipulation, eroded the purchasing power of ordinary citizens. The SOEs, while generating revenue for the state, led to corruption and inefficiency, as government officials and their cronies exploited their control over essential commodities. Moreover, these policies fueled social unrest, as merchants and commoners bore the brunt of the economic hardship. The famous Salt and Iron Debates (鹽鐵論) during the reign of Emperor Zhao illustrate the widespread discontent with these policies. Scholars and officials argued vehemently against government intervention in the economy, advocating for a return to a more laissez-faire approach. They pointed to the decline in the quality of goods produced by SOEs, the rise in prices, and the corruption that had become endemic in the government’s fiscal administration. While these debates ostensibly gave voice to the people’s grievances, they ultimately had little impact on government policy. The state’s dependence on SOEs and its control over currency had become too entrenched.

The consequences of Emperor Wu’s fiscal policies extended beyond the economic realm. The creation of SOEs and the focus on generating revenue through non-traditional means led to a shift in power dynamics within the government. The traditional bureaucracy, rooted in Confucian ideals of meritocracy and service, was gradually weakened. New positions, often filled by those with commercial expertise rather than scholarly credentials, gained prominence. This, combined with the increasing financial strain on the empire, created an environment ripe for corruption and factionalism. The eventual rise of eunuchs, often entrusted with managing the emperor’s finances and controlling access to his person, further undermined the authority of the traditional bureaucracy. These eunuchs, unconstrained by Confucian ethics and motivated by self-interest, often used their position to amass wealth and influence, further exacerbating the empire’s fiscal woes. Thus, the seeds of instability sown by Emperor Wu’s fiscal policies would continue to bear bitter fruit for centuries to come.

Part 2: Tang Dynasty: Fiscal Decentralization and the Rise of Warlords

The Tang Dynasty, often hailed as a golden age of Chinese civilization, presents a fascinating paradox: a period of remarkable economic and cultural flourishing alongside persistent fiscal weakness. At the heart of this paradox lies the Tang’s land allocation system, a seemingly simple yet ultimately flawed mechanism that shaped the dynasty’s trajectory. In theory, the system, inherited from the Sui Dynasty and rooted in the “equal-field system” (均田制), aimed to ensure equitable land distribution and a stable tax base. Each adult male was entitled to a plot of land from the state, obligated to pay taxes and perform labor service (庸) in return. Upon death, the land would revert to the state for redistribution. This system, known as the zuyongdiao (租庸調) system, also included a household tax (調) paid in goods like silk or cloth.

However, the Tang’s land allocation system, like its predecessors, was quickly riddled with loopholes. The very premise of state ownership and redistribution proved difficult to enforce. As population grew and land became scarce, powerful families and officials began to amass landholdings far exceeding the prescribed limits. Furthermore, many individuals sought to evade taxes and labor service by registering as dependents (客戶) of wealthy households or by taking on other exempt statuses, such as becoming monks or nuns. This led to a decline in the state’s tax base and a growing disparity between the wealthy elite and the common people. The government’s attempts to curb land privatization and tax evasion, through edicts and periodic land surveys, proved largely ineffective. The allure of profit and the inherent difficulties in enforcing a complex, centralized system across a vast empire consistently undermined these efforts.

Adding to the Tang’s fiscal woes was its unusual system of “self-funded” government agencies (公廨田, 公廨钱). Unable to adequately fund its bureaucracy through regular tax revenue, the Tang government implemented a system where each agency received a grant of land (公廨田) and money (公廨钱) and was expected to generate its own operating expenses through leasing the land and lending the money at interest. This system, while innovative in its attempt to create financial independence for government agencies, often backfired spectacularly. Officials, untrained in financial management, often made poor lending decisions, resulting in significant losses of public funds. Moreover, the pressure to generate revenue led to predatory lending practices, further burdening the populace and fueling social unrest.

This system became the center of a heated debate in 638 CE, highlighted by the controversy surrounding the zhuoqian lingshi (捉钱令史), clerks specifically tasked with managing these agency funds. Critics, such as the Confucian scholar and official Chu Suiliang (褚遂良), argued that this practice of entrusting financial matters to low-ranking clerks not only undermined the dignity of the civil service but also opened the door to corruption. They further pointed to the disproportionate number of zhuoqian lingshi positions compared to regular civil service posts, arguing that this created a perverse incentive for individuals to pursue these financially lucrative roles rather than seeking positions of genuine public service. Emperor Taizong, caught between the need for revenue and the growing criticism of the system, vacillated between supporting and abolishing it, highlighting the government’s precarious fiscal position.

The Tang’s inability to establish a stable and efficient fiscal system had far-reaching political consequences. The central government’s chronic lack of funds weakened its authority, making it increasingly reliant on powerful regional governors (節度使) for both revenue and military support. Initially created to manage border defenses, these jiedushi gradually accumulated power, controlling not only military forces but also civil administration and tax collection within their territories. This decentralization of power, driven by fiscal necessity, eroded the central government’s control over the empire. The jiedushi, while nominally subordinate to the emperor, became increasingly autonomous, often acting as de facto rulers within their domains. This power vacuum created by the weakened central government and the rise of the jiedushi ultimately paved the way for the An Lushan Rebellion in 755 CE, a devastating civil war that marked the beginning of the Tang Dynasty’s decline. An Lushan, a powerful jiedushi of Sogdian and Turkic origin, exploited the Tang’s internal weakness and launched a rebellion that plunged the empire into chaos, highlighting the dangerous consequences of fiscal decentralization and the unchecked power of regional warlords. The Tang’s seemingly simple fiscal system, riddled with loopholes and plagued by inefficiency, had not only failed to generate the revenue needed to maintain a strong central government but had also inadvertently created the conditions for its own demise.

Part 3: Song and Yuan Dynasties: The Paper Money Rollercoaster

The Song Dynasty (960-1279), a period of immense cultural and economic dynamism, also witnessed a pivotal moment in financial history: the birth of paper money. While the Tang had utilized promissory notes and other forms of credit, the Song’s jiaozi (交子) marked the true emergence of paper currency as a widespread medium of exchange. However, this innovation, initially a private invention born out of necessity, became a double-edged sword in the hands of the state, offering both unprecedented financial flexibility and the potential for catastrophic economic collapse. The story of paper money in the Song and Yuan dynasties is a rollercoaster ride of booms and busts, illustrating the seductive yet dangerous power of this new financial tool.

The Song Dynasty inherited a fragmented monetary system from the Five Dynasties and Ten Kingdoms period. Different regions used various forms of currency, including copper coins, iron coins, and even bolts of silk. Sichuan province, known for its thriving commerce but hampered by the weight and low value of iron currency, became the birthplace of jiaozi. Private merchants, recognizing the inconvenience of transporting large quantities of iron coins, began issuing promissory notes as deposit receipts. These notes, initially representing a specific amount of deposited iron currency, could be redeemed at the issuing merchant’s shop. However, their convenience quickly led to their use as a medium of exchange, circulating beyond the original depositors.

As jiaozi gained wider acceptance, the system’s inherent vulnerabilities became apparent. Unregulated private issuance led to overprinting and counterfeiting, eroding public trust and causing financial instability. Recognizing the need for intervention, the government stepped in, initially by limiting the number of authorized issuing merchants and later by nationalizing jiaozi production entirely. The state-run Jiaoziwu (交子務), established in 1023, aimed to stabilize the system by implementing reserves and imposing limits on issuance. Each jiaozi was theoretically backed by a certain amount of iron currency, and new issues were linked to the redemption and destruction of older notes. This, combined with strict penalties for counterfeiting, initially restored confidence in the currency.

However, the government’s fiscal woes, particularly the growing expenses of wars against the Western Xia and later the Jin Dynasty, proved too tempting to resist. The ease of printing money offered a seemingly painless solution to budget shortfalls. Gradually, the government abandoned its commitment to reserves and began printing jiaozi in excess of its iron currency holdings. This, combined with the expansion of jiaozi circulation beyond Sichuan, fueled inflation and eroded the currency’s value. Attempts to control the situation, such as issuing new denominations and forcing the exchange of older notes at unfavorable rates, only exacerbated the problem, undermining public trust and leading to financial panic.

The Yuan Dynasty (1271-1368), founded by Kublai Khan, inherited and expanded the Song’s experiments with paper money. Inspired by the convenience and revenue potential witnessed by Marco Polo, the Yuan government issued several forms of paper currency, including the Zhongtong Chao (中統鈔) and later the Zhida Chao (至元鈔). However, the Yuan government, like its Song predecessors, struggled to maintain fiscal discipline. Military campaigns, lavish court expenditures, and the costs of maintaining a vast empire strained the treasury, driving the government to print paper money with little regard for reserves. The result was a familiar cycle of inflation, devaluation, and the issuance of new currency denominations at increasingly unfavorable exchange rates.

Enter Toghto (脫脫), a brilliant and ambitious Yuan official who rose to the position of Grand Chancellor. Facing a declining economy and growing social unrest in the mid-14th century, Toghto embarked on an ambitious program of reforms aimed at revitalizing the Yuan Dynasty. His approach, reminiscent of modern Keynesian economics, focused on stimulating economic growth through government spending. He initiated large-scale infrastructure projects, including the repair of the Grand Canal and other waterworks, aiming to boost employment and agricultural production. He also implemented programs to promote rice cultivation in the north and improve military readiness.

However, Toghto’s ambitious plans faced a critical constraint: the Yuan government’s already depleted treasury. Undeterred, Toghto turned to the printing press, issuing vast quantities of a new paper currency, the Zhizheng Chao (至正钞), to finance his reforms. While initially cautious, setting a relatively modest exchange rate with older currency, the government soon abandoned restraint. The sheer scale of Toghto’s projects, coupled with ongoing military expenditures and the costs of suppressing rebellions, fueled a printing frenzy. Millions of banknotes flooded the market, driving prices skyward and decimating the currency’s value. Inflation spiraled out of control, reaching levels that made paper money practically worthless. Contemporary accounts describe banknotes piled up in the streets, discarded like trash, as people resorted to barter or used other forms of exchange.

Toghto’s economic stimulus, while well-intentioned, backfired spectacularly. Hyperinflation, the direct consequence of his unrestrained money printing, devastated the economy, exacerbating social unrest and weakening the Yuan government’s ability to maintain order. His reforms, instead of revitalizing the dynasty, arguably hastened its demise. The collapse of the monetary system, coupled with widespread economic hardship, fueled rebellions across the empire, culminating in the Red Turban Rebellion and the eventual overthrow of the Yuan Dynasty by Zhu Yuanzhang, the founder of the Ming Dynasty. Toghto’s story serves as a cautionary tale about the perils of government-led economic stimulus fueled by unchecked money printing, a lesson that continues to resonate in the modern era.


Guo Jianlong’s Decoding the Fiscal Secrets of the Central Empire offers a powerful lens through which to view the long sweep of Chinese history. The book convincingly argues that the fiscal health of a dynasty is often the key to its longevity, and that seemingly modern economic tools like SOEs, public land ownership, and financial monopolies have been used for millennia to consolidate state power and fund imperial ambitions. From the Han Dynasty’s reliance on salt and iron monopolies and currency manipulation to the Tang’s ill-fated experiment with self-funded government agencies, the book reveals recurring cycles of fiscal innovation, overreach, and eventual collapse. The Song and Yuan dynasties’ struggles with paper money illustrate the seductive power—and devastating consequences—of uncontrolled currency printing, a lesson that resonates even today. Throughout, Guo emphasizes not just the economic impact of these fiscal policies, but also their profound political and social consequences, showing how they shaped power dynamics, fueled corruption, and ultimately contributed to the rise and fall of dynasties.

This book’s relevance to a modern American audience is undeniable. China’s current economic model, with its blend of state-controlled enterprises, tight control over land, and dominance of key financial sectors, often sparks debate and concern in the West. Decoding the Fiscal Secrets of the Central Empire provides crucial historical context for understanding these policies, demonstrating that they are not simply products of communist ideology, but rather deeply embedded in the Chinese statecraft tradition. The book’s exploration of historical parallels—like Toghto’s “stimulus” program in the Yuan Dynasty, which eerily mirrors some modern government spending initiatives—offers valuable insights into the potential pitfalls and unintended consequences of state intervention in the economy. By understanding these historical patterns, we can gain a more nuanced understanding of China’s current trajectory and its implications for the global economy.

Decoding the Fiscal Secrets of the Central Empire is not just for academics or history buffs; it’s a compelling read for anyone seeking a deeper understanding of China’s economic and political landscape. Guo Jianlong’s engaging narrative and insightful analysis make this complex history accessible to a wide audience. Highly recommended for anyone seeking to decipher the complexities of China’s past, present, and future. While currently unavailable on major English-language bookselling platforms, interested readers can explore Chinese online bookstores for the original Mandarin edition or investigate academic resources that discuss the book’s core arguments. The insights contained within are well worth the effort.


Stay Connected With Deep Stories From China

Subscribe to receive the latest articles by email.

Join 1,553 other subscribers
Author

评论

Stay Connected With Deep Stories From China

Subscribe to PandaYoo now to continue reading the full article.
(English Version Only)

Join 1,553 other subscribers

Continue reading